Note F. On Page 269.
The Economy
{343} FOR the Economy, considered as a rule of practice, I shall refer
to what I wrote upon it in 1830-32, in my History of the
Arians. I have shown
above, pp. 26, 27, that the doctrine in question had in the early Church a large signification, when applied to the
divine ordinances: it also had a definite application to the duties of
Christians, whether clergy or laity, in preaching, in instructing or
catechizing, or in ordinary intercourse with the world around them;
and in this aspect I have here to consider it.
As Almighty God did not all at once introduce the Gospel to the
world, and thereby gradually prepared men for its profitable reception,
so, according to the doctrine of the early Church, it was a duty, for
the sake of the heathen among whom they lived, to observe a great
reserve and caution in communicating to them the knowledge of "the
whole counsel of God." This cautious dispensation of the truth,
after the manner of a discreet and vigilant steward, is denoted by the
word "economy." It is a mode of acting which comes under the
head of Prudence, one of the four Cardinal Virtues.
The principle of the Economy is this; that out of various courses, in
religious conduct or statement, all and each allowable antecedently
and in themselves, that ought to be taken which is most expedient
and most suitable at the time for the object in hand.
Instances of its application and exercise in Scripture are such as
the following:—1. Divine Providence did but {344} gradually impart to the
world in general, and to the Jews in particular, the knowledge of His
will:—He is said to have "winked at the times of ignorance among
the heathen;" and He suffered in the Jews divorce "because of
the hardness of their hearts." 2. He has allowed Himself to be
represented as having eyes, ears, and hands, as having wrath, jealousy,
grief, and repentance. 3. In like manner, our Lord spoke harshly to the
Syro-Phœnician woman, whose daughter He was about to heal, and made as
if He would go further, when the two disciples had come to their
journey's end. 4. Thus too Joseph "made himself strange to his
brethren," and Elisha kept silence on request of Naaman to bow in
the house of Rimmon. 5. Thus St. Paul circumcised Timothy, while he
cried out "Circumcision availeth not."
It may be said that this principle, true in itself, yet is dangerous,
because it admits of an easy abuse, and carries men away into what
becomes insincerity and cunning. This is undeniable; to do evil that
good may come, to consider that the means, whatever they are, justify
the end, to sacrifice truth to expedience, unscrupulousness,
recklessness, are grave offences. These are abuses of the Economy. But
to call them economical is to give a fine name to what occurs
every day, independent of any knowledge of the doctrine of the
Economy. It is the abuse of a rule which nature suggests to every one.
Every one looks out for the "mollia tempora fandi," and for "mollia verba" too.
Having thus explained what is meant by the Economy as a rule of
social intercourse between men of different religious, or, again,
political, or social views, next I will go on to state what I
said in the Arians.
I say in that Volume first, that our Lord has given us the principle
in His own words,—"Cast not your pearls before swine;" and
that He exemplified it in His teaching {345} by parables; that St. Paul
expressly distinguishes between the milk which is necessary to one set
of men, and the strong meat which is allowed to others, and that, in two
Epistles. I say, that the Apostles in the Acts observe the same rule in
their speeches, for it is a fact, that they do not preach the high
doctrines of Christianity, but only "Jesus and the Resurrection" or "repentance and faith." I also say, that this
is the very reason that the Fathers assign for the silence of various
writers in the first centuries on the subject of our Lord's divinity. I
also speak of the catechetical system practised in the early Church, and
the disciplina arcani as regards the doctrine of the Holy
Trinity, to which Bingham bears witness; also of the defence of this
rule by Basil, Cyril of Jerusalem, Chrysostom, and Theodoret.
But next the question
may be asked, whether I have said any thing in my Volume to guard
the doctrine, thus laid down, from the abuse to which it is obviously
exposed: and my answer is easy. Of course, had I had any idea that I
should have been exposed to such hostile misrepresentations, as it has
been my lot to undergo on the subject, I should have made more direct
avowals than I have done of my sense of the gravity and the danger of
that abuse. Since I could not foresee when I wrote, that I should have
been wantonly slandered, I only wonder that I have anticipated the
charge as fully as will be seen in the following extracts.
For instance, speaking of the Disciplina Arcani, I say:—(1) "The
elementary information given to the heathen or catechumen was in no
sense undone by the subsequent secret teaching, which was in fact
but the filling up of a bare but correct outline," p. 58,
and I contrast this with the conduct of the Manichæans "who
represented the initiatory discipline as founded on a fiction or
hypothesis, which was to be forgotten by the learner as he made progress
in the real {346} doctrine of the Gospel." (2) As to allegorizing,
I say that the Alexandrians erred, whenever and as far as they proceeded
"to obscure the primary meaning of Scripture, and to weaken
the force of historical facts and express declarations," p. 69.
(3) And that they were "more open to censure," when, on
being "urged by objections to various passages in the
history of the Old Testament, as derogatory to the divine perfections or
to the Jewish Saints, they had recourse to an allegorical explanation
by way of answer," p. 71. (4) I add, "It is impossible
to defend such a procedure, which seems to imply a want of faith
in those who had recourse to it;" for "God has given us rules
of right and wrong," ibid. (5) Again, I say,—"The
abuse of the Economy in
the hands of unscrupulous reasoners, is
obvious. Even the honest controversialist or teacher will find it
very difficult to represent, without misrepresenting, what it is
yet his duty to present to his hearers with caution or reserve. Here the
obvious rule to guide our practice is, to be careful ever to maintain
substantial truth in our use of the economical method," pp. 79, 80.
(6) And so far from concurring at all hazards with Justin, Gregory, or Athanasius, I say, "It is plain [they] were justified or not in their Economy, according
as they did or did not practically mislead their opponents,"
p. 80. (7) I proceed, "It is so difficult to hit the mark in these
perplexing cases, that it is not wonderful, should these or other
Fathers have failed at times, and said more or less than was
proper," ibid.
The Principle of the Economy is familiarly acted on among us every
day. When we would persuade others, we do not begin by treading on their
toes. Men would be thought rude who introduced their own religious
notions into mixed society, and were devotional in a drawing-room. Have
we never thought lawyers tiresome who did not observe this
polite rule, who came down for the assizes and talked law all
through dinner? Does the same argument {347} tell in the House of Commons, on
the hustings, and at Exeter Hall? Is an educated gentleman never worsted
at an election by the tone and arguments of some clever fellow, who,
whatever his shortcomings in other respects, understands the common
people?
As to the Catholic Religion in England at the present day, this only
will I observe,—that the truest expedience is to answer right out,
when you are asked; that the wisest economy is to have no management;
that the best prudence is not to be a coward; that the most damaging
folly is to be found out shuffling; and that the first of virtues is to
"tell truth, and shame the devil."
Top | Contents | Biographies
| Works |
Home
Newman Reader Works of John Henry Newman
Copyright © 2007 by The National Institute for Newman Studies. All rights reserved.
|